Grundrisse. 3. Production and Consumption

in #economics5 years ago

Grundrisse. 3. Production and Consumption

Marx lays out the phases of economic life. They are: production, distribution, exchange and consumption.

For bourgeois economists, incapable of grasping relations of a totality (dialectics), each phase appears as separate entities.

I'll be quoting much from Marx. He states it better than I can, and more succinctly. I'm hoping these posts to be commentary or summarization when the original text is enough on its own. This section serves as an almost guide to economics anyway, assailable even by folks unfamiliar with economic vocabulary. For other more obtuse parts of the text, I'll give more of a commentary on it. For this section, I'll be quoting a lot from Marx in full.

The obvious, trite notion: in production the members of society appropriate (create, shape) the products of nature in accord with human needs; distribution determines the proportion in which the individual shares in the product; exchange delivers the particular products into which the individual desires to convert the portion which distribution has assigned to him; and finally, in consumption, the products become objects of gratification, of individual appropriation. Production creates the objects which correspond to the given needs; distribution divides them up according to social laws; exchange further parcels out the already divided shares in accord with individual needs; and finally, in consumption, the product steps outside this social movement and becomes a direct object and servant of individual need, and satisfies it in being consumed

There are four phases of economic life: production, distribution, exchange, consumption. In contemporary capitalist society, consumption is seen as the primary point of existence. Consumption is divine. The ability to consume determines one’s self worth: consuming in extravagance is seen as the definition of success.

To reiterate the definitions.

Production: transforming nature into a product in accord with human need
Distribution: the proportion of individual shares in the social product
Exchange: delivering the product in proportion as distribution has determined
Consumption: product as object of gratification, individual appropriation

Thus production, distribution, exchange and consumption form a regular syllogism; production is the generality, distribution and exchange the particularity, and consumption the singularity in which the whole is joined together. This is admittedly a coherence, but a shallow one. Production is determined by general natural laws, distribution by social accident, and the latter may therefore promote production to a greater or lesser extent; exchange stands between the two as formal social movement; and the concluding act, consumption, which is conceived not only as a terminal point but also as an end-in-itself, actually belongs outside economics except in so far as it reacts in turn upon the point of departure and initiates the whole process anew.

This syllogism, of a beginning and clear end, is shallow in its grasp of totality. Marx responds to each component of the bourgeois syllogism and explains why each part is in truth its opposite. This section is a good example of a dialectical method in action.

Production
Production is also consumption. There are two aspects of that consumption: subjective and objective.

Subjective consumption refers to the way the individual laborer expends their own energy while producing a commodity. This should be well understood by anyway exhausted after the work day.

Objective consumption refers to the consumption of the means of production when producing a commodity. This is evident to anyone who has worked in a kitchen, for example. The use of a kitchen knife, over and over, re-sharpening it each time the blade dulls, eventually leads to a thin replica of what it once was.

Or, more simply, machines break down.

Production is also objective consumption in the sense that the natural elements available to the laborer are used up. They are consumed by the labor process in the production of a commodity.

A wooden table consumes trees to create the wood.

The act of production is therefore in all its moments also an act of consumption. But the economists admit this. Production as directly identical with consumption, and consumption as directly coincident with production, is termed by them productive consumption. This identity of production and consumption amounts to Spinoza’s thesis: determinatio est negatio. [11]

Determinatio est negatio. Determination is negation. Determination, declaring something as X, is negation. How can determination be something negative, and not positive? Calling a ‘cat’ a ‘cat’ is declarative, positive, right? In order for something to BE, it has to NOT BE something else. Being is negation of not-being. This kind of thinking, of how something can become its opposite, is dialectics.

Production, creating something, as consumption, negating something, is an example of how something can be its opposite.

  1. Consumption
    Just as production is consumption, the opposite is also true. Consumption is production. Consuming chemical and elements through metabolic processes, the plant produces more of itself and grows. This would be ‘consumptive production’. There is a mediation between consumption and production. You can only consume what is produced. The manner of production determines the manner of consumption (in order to ‘consume’ a gun, you need to pull the trigger). Consumption also mediates production, as consuming (using) the commodity is what realizes the productive process as production. Consumption is the moment of realization. If a commodity is never consumed, the entire chain of production/distribution/exchange is not REALIZED.

A railway on which no trains run, hence which is not used up, not consumed, is a railway only δυνάμει (potentially)

So consumption mediates production by realizing it as production. Consumption is the action through which the product becomes a product. Consumption also creates the need for new production. When you eat something, its gone, and a new commodity is required to be produced.

If it is clear that production offers consumption its external object, it is therefore equally clear that consumption ideally posits the object of production as an internal image, as a need, as drive and as purpose. It creates the objects of production in a still subjective form. No production without a need. But consumption reproduces the need

Production and consumption mediate one another. They are each other’s opposites, and at the same time, related in a unity. Production determines how consumption acts. Consumption also determines how production occurs.

Firstly, the object is not an object in general, but a specific object which must be consumed in a specific manner, to be mediated in its turn by production itself. Hunger is hunger, but the hunger gratified by cooked meat eaten with a knife and fork is a different hunger from that which bolts down raw meat with the aid of hand, nail and tooth. Production thus produces not only the object but also the manner of consumption, not only objectively but also subjectively. Production thus creates the consumer

The need which consumption feels for the object is created by the perception of it. The object of art – like every other product – creates a public which is sensitive to art and enjoys beauty. Production thus not only creates an object for the subject, but also a subject for the object. Thus production produces consumption (1) by creating the material for it; (2) by determining the manner of consumption; and (3) by creating the products, initially posited by it as objects, in the form of a need felt by the consume

The consumer is created by production. Consumption creates the need through which production can satisfy. The material basis for consumption is satisfied through production, which is always a specific production satisfying a specific need. There is never production in general, as that can only ever be an abstraction, just as there is no general consumption. A commodity creates its own use-base, just as an audience is created by the production of an art piece. Before that art, there was no audience for it.

each supplies the other with its object (production supplying the external object of consumption, consumption the conceived object of production);

...but also, each of them, apart from being immediately the other, and apart from mediating the other, in addition to this creates the other in completing itself, and creates itself as the other

Production and consumption have a mutual dependence. One can’t exist without the other. They supply the object for one another. Production gives the external object of consumption. Consumption gives the object of production (to be used).

Producers, however, do not freely consume their own product of labor. The product is outside them, external to them. They consume the products of their labor as mediated through distribution and exchange.

Sort:  

Due to how, in my words, self-explanatory the passage is, you obviously didn’t have to commentate that much on the passage other connecting the obvious. And I don’t have to give an Gregory B. Sadler (of ReasonIO) analysis nor background explanatiob to this passage either. So it works out well as, I think we can all safely say, a resting passage, though we should be critical of what Marx says. Of course critical not in the “wah! why wasn’t this talked?” but in the “okay, I see your point and I understand where this is going.” So I can safely sit down and just enjoy reading; the only thing I would commentate before we go any further: people read the previous two parts that @dirge made. Trust me, it’ll help yah to read them.

So in that way, let’s commerate the passage by talking about Dialectics for a bit. We should obviously start with the baseline assumption of uppercase D Dialectics; that assumption being that everything is ever-changing and that you can’t view/analyze and object in isolation. Now why was this important to announce right away, because uppercase M Metaphysics is the direct opposite with its baseline assumption: things are static and can be viewed in isolation / a void. With that, let’s get the limbs of Dialectics: supersessions (negations and positive kinds), quantity-quality, unity and interpentration of things and helical history.

Negative Supersessions were covered well in this post, but of the positive kind this needs only a special attention here. Positives are two-fold in nature: it can bring back an object from a previous stage and/or it can reaffirm something in new conditions. Now why the hazy distinction, what determines which is which? The former case it simply an accidental (id est contingent) result of a Negative Supersession when it has negated something but negates not the parts connected to it (or it at least not yet). The latter case stands more for antinomies and updating things. In the first case, imagine how the debates for free will and determinism where in the past and look at it now; for sure the debate maybe the same, but the categories had definitely expanded and changed. The second case is just a more general, abstract sense of Positive Supersessions that don’t negate things but brings it into the present.

Now quantity-quality, this one will be fast one. Basically this is purely transformations: qualities determine quantities, quantities can be transformed into qualities, a quality belongs to whole sorts of quantities and even a quantity has a quality all its own (as to quote Joseph Vissarionovich Stalin). The latter two are explanatory: the first simply because, let’s say exempli gratia, the colour “white” can be found in snow, types of napkins, colour itself, chinaware and so on and so on; the second simply because a quantity cannot exist without a definite quality (or to really say, there’s no object without a defining feature nor can an object not be able to effect things). The former two do however need some explaining. Qualities determining quantities is rather straightfoward except in how it does it; how it does it is in the fact that it brands universal traits into an object that gives it both determinancy and can differentiate itself from another very similar object. The talk of quantity transforming to quality follows this rather simple formulation: after so much small quantitative changes, there are times when that alone could lead to qualitative leaps. Exempli gratia, small inventions (which has a quality of its own) can lead to bigger and more defining inventions. Dialectics, they’re crazy!

Now let’s get to the Unity and Interpenetration of objects. Things are united in the fact that if they contradict each other, there is a struggle between the two. Exempli gratia, Prole-Bourgeois class struggle. Yet things interpenetrate each other in that things are permissible and have overlap. Class struggle couldn’t happen if there wasn’t a medium between the two that they interact with each other nor if they didn’t have the same objects of concern they are trying to win. The most simple and complex medium is the physical Réal we all exist in: the molecules that makes and surrounds us, the noises that are created when molecules vibrate and the molecules that can give and take life away is this very medium. Yet there’s another medium the class struggle operates on, Relations of Production (RoP): the Bourgeoisie has the Means of Productions (MoP) and the Prole not; the Prole wants, as the Working class, the MoP and the Bourgeoisie, as the Ruling class, will die to maintain their mastery over the MoP. And of course I could go on to show how the medium of Class Conflict truly unites the two as the interpenetration of the two, but that’s another theoritical thing for another time, since I covered two major mediums that lie within Class Conflict.

Finally, helical history. For the Dialectician (from the Hegelians to Marxists), history isn’t linear but instead helical. That’s because history isn’t where things get progressively more complex, that’s to delegitimize the complexity of life before us, the complexity of the formation of planets and even the complexity big bang! Nor do we have an idealized notion of a “true” beginning; we can always figure out what came before, but there isn’t a definite beginning beginning. However we can still claim the big bang happen, because it doesn’t contradict helical history, and it’s the last thing we could theorize that started this Universe. However there could be things that happened before the big bang like a universe (or many universes) that proceeded before this current one, we all could’ve lived in a string (String Theory) of hypercondensed matter and so on and so on. We truly can never figure out the exact origin of everything, but we’re going to use what we have now to figure out things that proceeded us before hand and what do in our current situations as to alleviate very actual problems. Anyways, I say helical because, despite not being able to prove a “true beginning,” that doesn’t mean the shape is linear now. It’s helical for three reasons: cycles (positive supersessions), aufheben (supersession, but more of the negative kind) and contingencies. Cycles are that: things that loop forever until they are broken or resolved; thus we can get the talks of “first as tragedy, second as farce” and what nots. (The quote coming from Karl Marx’s Brumierre where he talks abour Napoleon as the tragedy and Napoleon III as the farce; Napoleon made history and Napoleon III wanted to relive that in new conditions.) As aforementioned, aufheben (supersession) was already talked about here. And finally contingencies, or the happy accidents of (documented) history and life. Now to imagine a contingency, imagine helical history as a double helix: one helix is Positive Supersessions (cycles) the other Negative Supersessions (aufheben). With that in mind, the contingency is the pouring radiation that strikes the double helix and mutates history! Anyways, to make serious on this talk, contingencies are more than happy accidents that have suprising determinable powers; I mean how can they have such determinancy in their pockets? Contingencies take on a life of their own due to the fact that it actually is more or less the overlap of many necessities (Laws) playing at hand that it creates a life of its own. This overlap, confused and wisping by, has, as aforementioned, radioactive powers but also the distress of necessities overlapping each other. Which, nevertheless, wouldn’t sound crazy if I can say: “contingencies presuppose their own necessities.” And with all this informing (reflexive) History that transcribes a (documented) history, (documented) history in the eyes of (reflexive) History is Chaotic and Orderly at the same time.

Wheezing and with all this, I think this is the ultimate notes I could give on Dialectics. Lies down okay, I think that’ll be enough dialecticting today. Drinks some peckin’ fruit juice okay, have a red day. Upvot’d and resteem’d!
D8F10EF2-ACA7-442A-93A4-00E8E675EBC1.gif

you're certainly unenthusiastic about this topic

Yeah, that’s a given alright.



This post has been rated by the user-run curation platform CI! In this platform users are able to manually curate content. This is done regardless of Steem Power, for both rewards and vote size calculation.

Join in at our site here!
https://collectiveintelligence.red/

Or join us on discord to interact with the community!
https://discord.gg/sx6dYxt



This post was submitted for curation by: @michaias
This post was given a rating of: 0.9895120314830774
This post was voted: 100%

Hello @dirge, thank you for sharing this creative work! We just stopped by to say that you've been upvoted by the @creativecrypto magazine. The Creative Crypto is all about art on the blockchain and learning from creatives like you. Looking forward to crossing paths again soon. Steem on!

Coin Marketplace

STEEM 0.29
TRX 0.12
JST 0.033
BTC 63855.79
ETH 3113.00
USDT 1.00
SBD 4.04